Jan 23: What is economic history? [de Vries]
- Paul David, "Historical Economics in the Long Run: Some Implications of Path- Dependence," in G.D. Snooks, ed., Historical Analysis in Economics (London, 1993), pp. 29-40 http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/2008_pdf/David_Historical.pdf
- Robert M. Solow (1985), "Economic History and Economics," American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 75 (May): 328-331 http://www.jstor.org/view/00028282/di950057/95p00934/0
- M. I. Finley (1970), "Aristotle and Economic Analysis," Past and Present, No. 47. (May), pp. 3-25 http://www.jstor.org/view/00312746/ap020049/02a00010/0
Jan 30: Modes of production [DeLong]
- Jared Diamond (1987), "The Invention of Agriculture: The Worst Mistake in the History of the Human Race," Discover http://www.environnement.ens.fr/perso/claessen/agriculture/mistake_jared_diamond.pdf
- M. I. Finley (1965), "Technical Innovation and Economic Progress in the Ancient World," Economic History Review, New Series, 18:1, pp. 29-45 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0117%281965%292%3A18%3A1%3C29%3ATIAEPI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1
- Peter Temin, "A Market Economy in the Early Roman Empire" http://sshi.stanford.edu/Seminars/Papers/classics/temin.pdf
- William Baumol (1990), "Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive," Journal of Political Economy 98:5(1) (Oct), pp. 893-921 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199010%2998%3A5%3C893%3AEPUAD%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Z
Feb 6: Malthus and the demographic transition [de Vries]
- Gregory Clark (2005), "The Logic of the Malthusian Economy," chapter 2 of A Farewell to Alms http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/2008_pdf/Clark-2.pdf
- Ronald Lee (2003), "The Demographic Transition: Three Centuries of Fundamental Change," Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(4), pages 167-190, Fall http://ideas.repec.org/a/aea/jecper/v17y2003i4p167-190.html
- Peter Passell and Jeremy Atack (1997), "Population Growth and Redistribution," in A New Economic View of American History (2nd ed., W. W. Norton, 1997), pp. 212-37 [ONLINE REFERENCE MISSING]
- Optional: Thomas Malthus, An Essay on the Principle of Population
Feb 13: The industrious revolution [de Vries]
- Jan de Vries (1994), "The Industrious Revolution and the Industrial Revolution," Journal of Economic History 54:2 (June), pp. 249-70 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28199406%2954%3A2%3C249%3ATIRATI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8
- Jan de Vries (1994), "How did Pre-industrial labour markets Function?" in George Grantham and Mary McKinnon, eds, Labour Market Evolution (London, Routledge, 1994), pp. 39-63 [REFERENCE]
- Hans-Joachim Voth, "Time and Work in Eighteenth-Century London," Journal of Economic History 58 (1998): 29-58 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28199803%2958%3A1%3C29%3ATAWIEL%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Y
- Gregory Clark Ch. 3 of A Farewell to Alms http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/2008_pdf/Clark-3.pdf
Feb 20: Early modern institutions [de Vries]
- Avner Greif (1989), "Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders," Journal of Economic History 49:4 (December), pp. 857-882 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28198912%2949%3A4%3C857%3ARACIMT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M
- Douglass North and Barry Weingast (1989), "Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England," Journal of Economic History 49:4 (December), pp. 803-832 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28198912%2949%3A4%3C803%3ACACTEO%3E2.0.CO%3B2-9
Feb 27: Early modern globalization [de Vries]
- [Memo Question(http://delong.typepad.com/teaching_spring_2006/2008/02/memo-question-2.html)
- Jeffrey Williamson and Kevin O'Rourke, "After Columbus: Explaining Europe's Overseas Trade Boom, 1500-1800," Journal of Economic History 62 (2002): 417-456 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8186
- Karl Marx, "The So-called Primitive Capital Accumulation," Capital, I, Part VIII, Chs 26-32 http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch26.htm
* Jan de Vries, "The Limits to Globalization in the Early Modern World," Economic History Review (forthcoming) http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/2008_pdf/devries_limits_of_globalization.pdf
Mar 5: Wars, colonies, canals, finance, and northwest European divergence [de Vries]
- Ralph Austen and Woodruf D. Smith (1992), "Private Tooth Decay as Public Economic Virtue: The Slave-Sugar Triangle, Consumerism, and European Industrialization," in Joseph E. Imkori and Stanely L. Engerman, eds., The Atlantic Slave Trade (Durham, Duke Univ. Press, 1992), pp. 183-203 [ONLINE REFERENCE MISSING]
- Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson (2005), "The Rise of Europe," American Economic Review 95 (2005) http://www.nber.org/papers/w9378
- Larry Neal, Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge, Cambidge, Univ Press, 1990), pp. 1-43, 118-40 [ONLINE REFERENCE MISSING]
- Jan de Vries, "Dutch Economic Growth in Comparative-Historical Perspective, 1500-2000," De Economist 148 (2000): 443-467 http://www.springerlink.com/content/l4qp2l551l7t7361/
Mar 12: Technology, investment, and the industrial revolution [DeLong]
- Nicholas Crafts (2002), "The Solow Productivity Paradox in Historical Perspective," (London: CEPR Discussion Paper no.3142) http://www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/DP3142.asp
- Maxine Berg and Pat Hudson, "Rehabilitating the Industrial Revolution," Economic History Review new ser. 45, pp.23-50 http://www.jstor.org/view/00130117/di011838/01p0208u/0
- Peter Temin, "Two Views of the British Industrial Revolution," Journal of Economic History 57, pp.63-82 http://ideas.repec.org/p/nbr/nberhi/0081.html
- Jeffrey Williamson, "Why Was British Economic Growth So Slow During the Industrial Revolution?" Journal of Economic History 44, pp.687-712 http://www.jstor.org/view/00220507/di975668/97p1230f/0
Mar 19: Marx and urbanization and industrialization and marketization [DeLong]
- Alfred D. Chandler (1992), "Organizational Capabilities and the Economic History of the Industrial Enterprise," Journal of Economic Perspectives 6 (Summer) http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0895-3309%28199222%296%3A3%3C79%3AOCATEH%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X
- Susan Wolcott and Gregory Clark (1999). "Why Nation's Fail: Managerial Decisions and Performance in Indian Cotton Textiles, 1890-1938." Journal of Economic History, June http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28199906%2959%3A2%3C397%3AWNFMDA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-9
- Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels (1848), "Manifesto of the Communist Party" http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/
Apr 2: Imperialism and colonialism [de Vries]
- W. Arthur Lewis, Evolution of the International Economic Order (Princeton, Princeton Univ. Press, 1978), pp. 2-25, 38-57 [ONLINE REFERENCE MISSING]
- Barry R. Chiswick and Timothy J. Hatton, "International Migration and the Integration of Labor Markets," in Michael Bord, Alan M. Taylor, and Jeffrey G. Williamson, Globalization in Historical Perspective (NBER 2003), pp. 65-120 http://books.google.com/books?id=vDL0u3Rz7C8C&pg=PA65&lpg=PA65&dq=chiswick+and+hatton+international+migration+and+the+integration+of+labor+markets&source=web&ots=TyVyvyVUrD&sig=uMpziuGPhgx3CC_cY2X5oEzuN6I
- Jeffry G. Williamson, "Globalization, Convergence, and History" Journal of Economic History 56 (1996):227-306 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28199606%2956%3A2%3C277%3AGCAH%3E2.0.CO%3B2-T
- Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff, "The Gold Standard as a 'Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval'" Journal of Economic History 56 (1996): 389-428 https://www.nber.org/papers/w5340
Apr 9: Why did the European settler colonies industrialize? [DeLong]
- Evsey Domar (1970), "The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A Hypothesis," Journal of Economic History, pp. 18-32 http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/movable_type/2003_archives/001447.html
- Stanley Engerman and Kenneth Sokoloff (1994), "Factor Endowments, Institutions and Differential Paths of Development Among New World Economies: A View from Economic Historians of the United States" (Cambridge: NBER Working Paper no. h0066) http://papers.nber.org/papers/h0066.pdf
- Peter Temin (1966), "Labor Scarcity and the Problem of American Industrial Efficiency in the 1850s," Journal of Economic History 26, pp. 277-298 http://www.jstor.org/view/00220507/di975596/97p0463m/0
- Claudia Goldin and Kenneth Sokoloff (1984), "The Relative Productivity Hypothesis of Industrialization: The American Case, 1820-1850," Quarterly Journal of Economics 99 (August), pp. 461-87 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28198408%2999%3A3%3C461%3ATRPHOI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-V
Apr 16: Gold standard and pre-WWI globalization [DeLong]
- Michael Bordo, "The Gold Standard" http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/GoldStandard.html
- Albert Fishlow (1985), "Lessons from the Past: Capital Markets During the 19th Century and the Interwar Period," International Organization 39, pp. 383-439, http://www.jstor.org/view/00208183/dm980251/98p00792/0
- Douglas Irwin (1998), "Did Late Nineteen Century U.S. Tariffs Promote Infant Industries? Evidence from the Tinplate Industry," NBER Working paper no. 6835 (December), http://www.nber.org/papers/w6835
- Barry Eichengreen, Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939, pp. xi-31, 34-39 http://books.google.com/books?id=Qk1flhynCD8C&pg=PA36&lpg=PA36&dq=gold+standard+rules+of+the+game+ragnar+nurkse&source=web&ots=ONUR57nl4M&sig=yPLXPtqeUlDBtlmU3zgpECPVAbU#PPA39,M1
- John Dutton (1983), "The Bank of England and the Rules of the Game under the International Gold Standard," in Michael Bordo and Anna Schwartz (eds), A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 173-195 http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=GT_S0mm3opEC&oi=fnd&pg=PR11&dq=Hugh+Rockoff,+Some+Evidence+on+the+Real+Price+of+Gold,+Its+Costs+of+Production,+and+Commodity+Prices,&ots=B1Ld-1e9HO&sig=v27mKZ0vpCy38AsN2E44lW2CKnQ#PPA173,M1
Apr 23: WWI and the Great Depression [DeLong]
- John Maynard Keynes (1920), The Economic Consequnces of the Peace, chapters 1, 2, and 6 http://www.gutenberg.org/files/15776/15776-h/15776-h.htm
- Christina Romer (1990), "The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression," Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, pp.719-736, http://www.jstor.org/view/00335533/di971078/97p00037/0
- Ben Bernanke (1983), "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression" American Economic Review 73, pp. 257-276, http://www.jstor.org/view/00028282/di950033/95p00602/0
- Paul Krugman, "Introduction" to John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money http://www.pkarchive.org/economy/GeneralTheoryKeynesIntro.html
- John Maynard Keynes (1932), "The World's Economic Outlook," Atlantic http://www.theatlantic.com/unbound/flashbks/budget/keynesf.htm
- Margaret Weir and Theda Skocpol, "State Structures and Social Keynesianism: Responses to the Great Depression in Sweden and the United States," International Journal of Comparative Sociology pp. 4-29 http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=GLQ3AAAAIAAJ&oi=fnd&pg=PA7-IA3&dq=Margaret+Weir+and+Theda+Skocpol,+%22State+Structures+and+Social+Keynesianism&ots=P2iXGFkFfu&sig=APmY6D1P2QkJ0l28RRWX5YxjBmg#PPA29,M1
Apr 30: WWII and the thirty glorious years [DeLong]
- Peter Temin (2002), "The Golden Age of European Growth Reconsidered," European Review of Economic History 6, pp. 33-22. http://www.international.ucla.edu/cms/files/Temin.pdf
- Mancur Olson (1996), "The Varieties of Eurosclerosis: The Rise and Decline of Nations Since 1982," in Nicholas Crafts and Gianni Toniolo (eds), Economic Growth in Europe Since 1945, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp.73-94 http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=wiTtnUn5qGsC&oi=fnd&pg=PA73&dq=%22OLSON%22+%223+The+varieties+of+Eurosclerosis:+the+rise+and+decline+...%22+&ots=s86KlJoXe7&sig=wabLIsaAIsicZhoppgt-vDhRxcE#PPA69,M1
- Barry Eichengreen, "Institutions and Economic Growth in Postwar Europe: Evidence and Conjectures" (with Pablo Vazquez), http://www.econ.berkeley.edu/~eichengr/research/vanark.pdf
- Richard Ericson, "The Classical Soviet-Type Economy: Nature of the System and Implications for Reform," Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (Fall 1991), pp. 11-28, http://uclibs.org/PID/1011
May 7: The twentieth-century experience: half empty or half full?
- Richard Easterlin (1981), "Why Isn't the Whole World Developed?" Journal of Economic History 41:1 (March), pp. 1-19 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28198103%2941%3A1%3C1%3AWITWWD%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Y
- Angus Maddison (1983), "A Comparison of Levels of GDP Per Capita in Developed and Developing Countries, 1700-1980," Journal of Economic History 43:1 (March), pp. 27-41 http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0507%28198303%2943%3A1%3C27%3AACOLOG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-3
- Lant Pritchett, "Divergence, Big Time," Journal of Economic Perspectives (Summer 1997), pp. 3-17, http://uclibs.org/PID/1011
- Dani Rodrik, "Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich," Economic Policy 20, (1995) pp. 55-107, http://papers.nber.org/papers/w4964.pdf
The articles this week provide several different explanations for the phenomenon of divergence. It is not difficult to show that there are serious problems and uncertainties with all of these explanations. I believe it would be interesting to focus on the phenomena of war/conflict and corruption in explaining divergence in a ‘flattened,’ more integrated world.
Divergence is documented in the article by Ritchett. His observation is straightforward: Among one group of countries, growth rates have been inversely related to GDP per capita at the start of the modern era (around 1870). These countries called, developed, have seen convergence. In contrast, outside of these countries, the pattern is absent. Many of these developing countries, despite their low initial incomes, have grown slower than developed countries, making their relative position to developed countries far worse than it was 140 years ago. I think it would be worth positing some statistical distributions where these phenomena are simply the outcome of a random process, but overall, in spite of some difficulties in showing divergence (e.g. assuming a lower bound for GDP per capita in developing countries and imputing pre-1950 GDP values) the divergence phenomena appears present. Maddison presents a challenge to Ritchett by arguing that Europe was already rich before the Industrial Revolution, so that there are fewer facts to be explained. Picking a side in this debate requires some understanding of the quality of past GDP data (which I do not have), so for this memo I will assume the existence of divergence.
Easterlin argues that divergence is caused by difference in the education level of different workforces; more educated populations can absorb and imitate technologies invented in other countries. His argument is primarily anecdotal instead of empirical. Though schooling is usually significant in cross-country growth regressions, the issue of causality is difficulty: Does schooling cause higher growth, or is schooling a luxury good that wealthier countries can afford? There are many highly educated countries that have had less than optimal growth records. I spent last summer in the Philippines, where I was told that around two thirds of college-age students are currently attending college (in the Barro-Lee schooling data the Philippines is very high, higher than many developed countries). However, the country as a whole is still relatively poor (and growth has been uneven). Instead of helping start new manufacturing firms at home, many educated Filipinos go to work abroad (this is a way that globalization may actually promote divergence by giving high-talent workers opportunities to leave their home countries).
Rodrik argues that Korea and Taiwan grew rich because of government policies that helped eliminate coordination failures. Challenging the export orientation argument in past literature on East Asian growth, Rodrik asserts that the strong central governments in Korea and China steered businessmen away from rent-seeking into socially-efficient forms of enterprise. His argument is both unorthodox and very interesting. However, it is difficult to extrapolate it relevance for understanding global divergence, as (notes Rodrik) many economies led by strong central governments have failed.
One casual observation in understanding divergence is that while North America and Western/Central Europe have enjoyed almost 60 years of tranquility, other parts of the world, particularly Africa, have seen years and years of war and conflict. Even if a country does not experience a war itself, having trading partners at war, and having foreign investors view one’s neighbors as being at war, is likely very detrimental for development. In a separate explanation, corruption is also much less significant in North America and Europe than in the developing world. In the Philippines, local people I talked to about the economy almost uniformly emphasized corruption as the source of their economic woes. Although much recent work in economics has analyzed both war and corruption, I would like to see both explanations used specifically to address the question of divergence.
Posted by: Mitchell Hoffman | May 07, 2008 at 12:43 AM